Chinese Economic Policy in the 21st Century: Growth, Imbalance, and Considerations for Australia

By Reuben NS. Tang
2013, Vol. 5 No. 08 | pg. 2/3 |

As a result, China possesses an absolute advantages in manufacturing vis-à-vis other regions. Thus, while the proportion of the working age-population declined by 0.1% in 2011, China still possesses a relatively large pool of labour it can draw upon. Some concerns are however raised by recent statistics indicating a slowdown in the number of migrant workers, causing average migrant worker income to increase by 21.2% versus 14.1% per annum over 2005-2010 (National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2011a, The Economist, 2012b, The Economist, 2012d, National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2011b).

With regard to productivity, modern Chinese economic policy is partly characterised by China’s relatively early dismantling of tariff barriers leading to acceptance of large quantities of foreign direct investment (FDI) and earlier engagement in international trade (Boltho and Weber, 2009). Net effects of this international engagement have allowed Chinese companies to take advantage of large flows of foreign capital whilst resulting in a transfer of foreign technologies and management practices (European Commission: Enterprise and Industry, 2004).

Branstetter and Lardy (2006) further reinforce this, stating that this relative openness to FDI has resulted in an earlier expansion of China’s service industry, representing a sharp contrast to other East Asian economies during their respective ages in development (Figure 3).

Figure 3: Foreign Trade GDP ratios (ratio of exports and imports of goods and services to GDP at current prices) (Boltho and Weber, 2009).

Figure 3

This influx of FDI and receptiveness to external practices has also led to an increase of multifactor productivity in China, though estimates vary regarding the degree of improvement. On one hand, Du & Yue, 2009 estimated a productivity improvement of 21% on a wage increase of 9.8% per annum from 2000 to 2007. On the other, estimates from the Asian Development Bank suggest an productivity improvement of 14% on a wage increase of 16% per annum from 2000 to 2010 (The Economist, 2011). Nevertheless, despite these varying estimates the general consensus is that an assymetry between wage and productivity growth exists: that the productivity to wage growth ratio remains relatively high vis-à-vis other regions (Figure 5; Knight et al., 2011).

Figure 4: Nominal production worker wages, adjusted for productivity ($ per hour)(Marsh, 2011).

Figure 4

Multiple authors have further argued that China’s growth is due to a significant domestic imbalance between household wealth and investment growth (figure 5), deflating the real cost of capital in China (figure 6; Hung, 2008, Pettis, 2011, Deer and Song, 2012). These authors have attributed this imbalance to ‘implicit taxation’ of households with increments in income and welfare taxes (figure 7), divergences in productivity and wage growth and an alleged undervaluation of its currency, leading to a net transfer of wealth from households to corporations (Deer and Song, 2012, International Monetary Fund, 2011, Reserve Bank of Australia, 2010, The Economist, 2012c).

Figure 5: China domestic demand in % of GDP (International Monetary Fund, 2012).

Figure 5

Figure 6: Real Cost of Capital (2005-9; International Monetary Fund, 2011).

Figure 6

Figure 7: China: Household Income Accounts (% of GDP; Reserve Bank of Australia, 2010).

Figure 7

It is further argued that this low cost of capital and pro-investment policies have contributed to overinvestment in key economic areas, characterised by rising investments rates in Fixed Asset Investments (FAI) until at least the onset of the US financial crisis (Figure 8). This overcapacity within China was masked by a rise in the growth rate of FAI and an accelerated growth rate of exports (Yu, 2009). As a result, growth was sustained at the expense of the widening imbalances between investments and private consumption. Until recently, the net result was that China’s economy became increasingly reliant on external demand, with the share of its current account surplus (mainly the trade surplus) in GDP rising rapidly (Figure 9).

Figure 8: Fixed asset investment growth in China.

Figure 8

Figure 9: Share of the current account surplus in GDP.

Figure 9

As a result of maintaining growth via exports, China runs large trade surpluses with the US and the EU, totalling 2.0trln USD (2003-11) and 780bln euro (2007-2011) respectively (U.S. Census Bureau, 2012, European Commission: Trade, 2012). An interventionist monetary and fiscal policy has kept inflation within tolerable limits via the heavy regulation of Chinese financial institutions resulting in a non-competitive financial sector (The Economist, 2012c). As a result, most corporations still mostly derive business finance through banks rather than through the issuance of financial securities (table 1). This hints at the possibility that the Chinese financial sector is only marginally developed, contributing to artificially low factor costs (International Monetary Fund, 2011, Richard and Burdekin, 2008).

Table 1: Financing sources for China’s Domestic Non-Financial Sector. Figures in billions of RMB; percentages in italics (The People's Bank of China, 2012).


2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003
Total 11,113.6 13,079.4 6,048.6 4,970.5 3,987.4 3,150.7 2,902.3 3,515.4

100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Bank Loans 8,357.2 10,522.5 4,985.4 3,920.5 3,268.7 2,461.7 2,406.6 2,993.6

75.2 80.5 82.4 78.9 82.0 78.1 82.9 85.2
Government Securities 973.5 818.2 102.7 179.0 267.5 299.6 312.6 352.5
8.8 6.3 1.7 3.6 6.7 9.5 10.8 10.0
Corporate Bonds 1,171.3 1,236.7 607.8 217.8 226.6 201.0 32.7 33.6
10.5 9.5 10.0 4.4 5.7 6.4 1.1 1.0
Equities 611.6 502.0 352.7 653.2 224.6 188.4 150.4 135.7

5.5 3.8 5.8 13.1 5.6 6.0 5.2 3.9

Beneficiaries of this increasing trade with China include countries with significant links to China such as the East Asian, South East Asian countries and Australia. These countries are generally large primary resource exporters, or specialise in manufacturing that China is unable to perform on an equivalent scale. In this regard, some argue that China acts as a major regional assembly centre for multinational corporations where countries export parts to China for final assembly only. On this note, in 2006 55% of China’s imports represented goods assembled from imported parts and components (Morrison and Labonte, 2011, Hufbauer et al., 2006). China’s trade surplus with the US and the EU may thus partially represent the trade surplus of the East Asian region (Jin and Li, 2007).

Suggested Reading from Inquiries Journal

John Howard, then-Prime Minister of Australia, claimed that, ‘I count it as one of the great successes of this country’s foreign relations that we have simultaneously been able to strengthen our long-standing... MORE»
Advertisement
Since 1989, when economist John Williamson first conceived of the economic and policy recommendations known as the Washington Consensus (Williamson, 1989), this Consensus became generally accepted as the most effective model by which developing nations could spur growth. Embracing ideals of free-market capitalism,... MORE»
This essay seeks to elucidate the puzzle of China's policy decision to create a Sovereign Wealth Fund (SWF). Much literature has been put forth on the topic to predict the strategic benefits China may be pursuing through its investments in American firms using its SWF, China Investment Corporation (CIC). Such speculation on these... MORE»
In 2001, Goldman Sachs named Brazil one of the four most important emerging economies, with China, Russia and India.1 The BRICs, a term coined by Jim O’Neill, are prophesized to become four of the top six economies in the world by 2050,2 and, with the United States, form a new core of power. O’Neill argued that if Brazil... MORE»
Submit to Inquiries Journal, Get a Decision in 10-Days

Inquiries Journal provides undergraduate and graduate students around the world a platform for the wide dissemination of academic work over a range of core disciplines.

Representing the work of students from hundreds of institutions around the globe, Inquiries Journal's large database of academic articles is completely free. Learn more | Blog | Submit

Follow IJ

Latest in Economics

2020, Vol. 12 No. 09
Recent work with the Economic Complexity Index (ECI) has shown that a country’s productive structure constrains its level of economic growth and income inequality. Building on previous research that identified an increasing gap between Latin... Read Article »
2018, Vol. 10 No. 10
The value proposition in the commercial setting is the functional relationship of quality and price. It is held to be a utility maximizing function of the relationship between buyer and seller. Its proponents assert that translation of the value... Read Article »
2018, Vol. 10 No. 03
Devastated by an economic collapse at the end of the 20th century, Japan’s economy entered a decade long period of stagnation. Now, Japan has found stable leadership, but attempts at new economic growth have fallen through. A combination of... Read Article »
2014, Vol. 6 No. 10
In July 2012, Spain's unemployment rate was above 20%, its stock market was at its lowest point in a decade, and the government was borrowing at a rate of 7.6%. With domestic demand depleted and no sign of recovery in sight, President Mariano Rajoy... Read Article »
2017, Vol. 9 No. 10
During the periods of the Agrarian Revolt and the 1920s, farmers were unhappy with the economic conditions in which they found themselves. Both periods witnessed the ascent of political movements that endeavored to aid farmers in their economic... Read Article »
2017, Vol. 7 No. 2
Published by Clocks and Clouds
In 2009, Brazil was in the path to become a superpower. Immune to the economic crises of 2008, the country's economy benefitted from the commodity boom, achieving a growth rate of 7.5 per cent in 2010, when Rousseff was elected. A few years later... Read Article »
2012, Vol. 2 No. 1
Published by Clocks and Clouds
The research completed aimed to show that the idea of fair trade, using the example of goals for the chocolate industry of the Ivory Coast, can be described as an example of the economic ideal which Karl Marx imagined. By comparing specific topics... Read Article »

What are you looking for?

FROM OUR BLOG

Finding Balance in Graduate School
How to Manage a Group Project (Video)
How to Use Regression Analysis Effectively