From Interstate - Journal of International Affairs VOL. 2013/2014 NO. 1 The Interests of Minority and Majority Shareholders in the EU
By Angelika Gorak
Interstate - Journal of International Affairs 2014, Vol. 2013/2014 No. 1 | pg. 1/2 | »
The recent economic crisis roved to be immensely threatening to the economic equilibrium within the European Union (EU). Beginning in the United States, it then proved its "domino effect" by covering the EU, resulting in so-called 'financial stress' in all the Member States.1 In this context, some possible explanations for the crisis are worth mentioning: unsustainable macroeconomic inequalities , a lack of adequate policies preventing adventurous risk-t aking on the global scale,2 a complete failure in the system of global financial governance and its regulatory framework.3 Many of these explanations point toward wrong decision-making on the part of majority shareholders. Had there been a proper system of internal checks and balances within the companies, the financial backlash would not have been as devastating to the economy.
The following piece explores a variety of mechanisms and principles that the EU uses to guard the interests of minority and majority shareholders-. The analysis shall be undertaken on several plains: the balance of power in the company; minority and majority shareholders-; and empowerment and protection. The underlying idea of this piece is to provide an overview of how the EU regulates the often clashing and overlapping interests of shareholders.
Minority shareholders are those board members that possess less than 50 per cent of the shareholdings in a company.4 There are two approaches to identifying this group. Firstly, the quantitative approach depends on the percentage of capital owned, though this is often regarded as outdated. Secondly, the qualitative approach considers that control is of utmost importance, an approach often regarded as more realistic.5 For the purposes of this piece, let us accept that the objective numerical disadvantage of minority shareholders naturally results in decsion making impotency within the business organisation.
A majority shareholder is-a person or a company that owns more than 50 per cent of the stock within companies, which usually allows them to control the company's transactions, and more importantly, elect the board of directors.6 Thus, they are in de facto control of the company, which entails deciding directly or indirectly on the salaries of the management, on dividends , causing a break-up of the corporation, deciding on the merger, cash-out public shareholders, amending the rules on incorporation and selling the assets.7
It must be noted that a shareholder who 'owns a majority interest' or 'exercises control' over the business or corporation is subject to fiduciary duty towards minority shareholders, which may be both directors and controlling stockholders.8 Thus, th e fiduciary duty, based on the trust between the trustee and the beneficiary , gives a sort of "security" to minority shareholders and also disengages controlling shareholders from 'self-dealing transactions'.9 In order to balance this striking inequality of roles, this fiduciary duty extends to all responsibilities given to controlling shareholders in case of breakup of the corporation, merger with another company, in case of cash-outs, selling of corporate assets and others. Furthermore, majority shareholders are subjects to the duty of care, which stands for acting in a good faith, with ordinary care and 'in a manner the director reasonably believes in the best interest of the corporation' .10
The crux of minority protection can be found in the antagonistic relationship between the controlling bodies of a company, including its directors and majority shareholders, and the reluctant minority shareholders, in case of a change in corporate control This balancing act could be viewed as a matter of survival in the "corporate jungle". Those who manage to usurp control are in the company's "driver's seat", creating the rules and possessing more comprehensive and solid influence. These problems are countered by minority protection and minority empowerment, which are two sides of the same coin. The former is about the intervention of the state, in its judicary or legislative capacity that is entrusted with modeling and enforcing the external legislative framework of controls . Nevertheless , this is not about the state "picking sides", since it is at no point directly accountable to the minority shareholders. Minority empowerment is about the internal checks and balances in the struggle for power and granting clear-cut rights to the minority within the business entity itself.11 This piece sees both interpretations as relevant for the purposes of outlining the interests of minority shareholders.
Traditionally , the minority shareholders' position is disadvantageous, being at a greater distance from the information flows and the decision-making process. In the case of cross-border mergers within the EU, for example, the situation is relatively more inclusive in terms of consultation, although the final choice is made by the majority shareholders. Nevertheless , in cross-border mergers, approval requires a positive vote cast at the general meetings of the totality of the concerned companies.
The conditions for equal treatment of minority and majority shareholders are better, since the process occurs at the same moment in time and under identical terms. However, the possibility of indirect benefits for the majority shareholders is not to be dismissed and, therefore, the question of what remedies are available for the minority is still relevant. Apparently, there are only two options left - filing for damages or selling the shares. Both options can result in monetary compensation.12
Although having been given an "assurance" in the duty of loyalty and duty of care, the minority shareholders at large still seems to have an antagonistic approach towards majority shareholders. The literature mainly focuses on the ways in which the majority shareholders may abuse their powers and "consume corporate wealth", for example by paying themselves excessive salaries, withdrawing funds, or blocking a value increasing tender. It may be rebutted, however, by the fact that in concentrated ownership model, the majority is directly involved in the management of the company. Thus, the majority shareholders play an active role in scrutinising the management. Furthermore, mechanisms such as corporate control trans actions, accounting rates of return of the company, a so-called transparency policy are available for the minority shareholders to prevent mismanagement13 More precisely, after a scandal related to Enron, the European Commission launched the Communication on the statutory audit followed by an Action Plan on Modernizing Company Law, focusing mainly on corporate governance enhancement and transparency.14 Furthermore, after the Parmalat insolvency issue - the collapse of a food and dairy corporation, which the BBC described as 'Europe 's biggest bankruptcy '15 - the reform s in the field of accounting and audit controls were necessary.
The scandal confirmed regulatory problems on both Member State and EU level. It unveiled that the European system attracted private benefits extraction; controlling shareholders have developed a variety of techniques to tunnel assets and profits. The collapse of Parmalat has made the EU realise that the accounting frauds and abuses coming from the board of directors were not solely an American problem.16 A need to introduce high quality company disclosure systems and regulations designed to protect investors were clearly missing in EU legislation. Therefore, the EU had been encouraging an adoption of the Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP), a United States-style corporate governance and securities law system. It has, however, struggled to create any measures on the national level, as various interest groups, national governments, have opposed it.17
Nevertheless, realistically, takeovers remains the trickiest of control transfers for vulnerable and powerless minority shareholders, since they are in the danger of becoming victims in a clash between titans, the target company and the one initiating the merger. First, they have no standing to bring action against the controller s for breach of fiduciary duty. Secondly, the Takeover Directive18 (or any European harmonisation instrument, for that matter) has failed to enlist specific rights belonging to or any express duties owed to this category of shareholders, nor does it speak of any legal bases for thos e. Thirdly, enforcement rules for regulatory offences are underdeveloped, because they do not cover private actions. Last, but not least, the legal system is not particularly favourable to law enforcement in relation to private investors.19
Joseph Lee20 explores the rationale behind the need to protect minority shareholders. The proprietary argument notes that shareholders entertain a proprietary interest in a company's investments. Their rights could be appraised as those of passive owners and residual claimants, or could be construed as active ones, retaining entitlement over dividends, votes, equal treatment, law suit and others. In the meantime, the contractarian point suggests that the minority shareholders enter a unanimous and voluntary agreement with the company. The terms of the contract, based on fiduciary principles of trust between a trustee and a beneficiary, have the power to raL'>e the price per share, if found favourable by investors. Furthermore, another theory is that the controlling actors owe a duty of care to their fellow minority board members. A fourth important hypothesis is that of corporate democracy. It concerns the legitimacy of the rule of the majority, and the paper-thin boundary between that and a regime where the will of the minority is ignored. Corporate democracy is envisioned as a process of deliberation, where all points of view are taken into account and equitable principles are respected. Last, but not least, the distributive justice argument rejects state intervention in a free competitive market Following the social meritocratic principle within the closed community of a company, even the minority shareholders should be entitled to reap the benefits of their contributions.
Lee proposes four general models of granting extra rights to minority shareholders, inspired by the English practice: internal control, market control, regulatory control and private action. The internal control pattern entails mechanisms inside the corporate structure, like board and general meetings. The underlying principle is that a company is master of its assets and the directors are bound to the company by means of a fiduciary duty. The privilege to bring action against the directors is conferred on the company. The minorit y shareholders may also start proceedings against directors by means of the doctrine of derivative actions originally coined in English law (Foss v Harbottle22).23 Almost all Continental European states, except for example the Netherlands, have accepted law suits by derivative shareholders. If damage sustained by negligence is inflicted on the company's assets, the shareholders can only sue in the company's name.
The shareholder can only liquidate the entire damage, not only the part equated to their stake. This mechanism has been designed to resolve the majority versus minority conflict: the wrongdoer enjoys the support of the majority in the general meeting, exercises "wrongdoer control", or is under the wing of the majority, should the breach of duty have benefited the controlling shareholder. Thus, a minority law suit reaffirms the principle of equal treatment of shareholders. However, problems arise where the interests of the company and those of the minority do not match.24
Lee's second model is the market control model In this case, the forces of supply and demand determine the price per share, which in turn is symptomatic of the management and performance of the company.25 Critics have established that there is indeed a correlation between those factors:
'Minority shareholders in countries whose laws promote and protect shareholder rights are probably more likely to be able to have the kinds of boards that they desire. In addition, corporate boards in countries where the law supports board oversight and actions are probably more likely to be effective. We hypothesise, therefore, that "good" shareholder laws and "good" boards go hand-in-hand, in the sense that they must be complements'.26
In order for this theory to work, shares sold in the market must comprise a substantial part of the total shareholdings. This trading must be done without any restraints and the company must be facing a takeover.27
With regards to markets which are subject to regulatory control, the state L'> the main actor, occasionally delegating to self-regulatory bodies of public authorities. It is a case of external supervision and inspection of mergers under a pre-established comprehensive framework. The state pursues the public interest, sometimes even at the expense of that of the shareholders or with a great deal of arbitrariness.28
The last model is the private actions model, which is most favoured by the authors. It is basically the right to a self-defence reaction in case harm is inflicted or unjust and inequitable treatment is demonstrated by the majority shareholders on the minority shareholders. It should be their prerogative to seek redress and compensation in court as well as cease the relevant authorities for malpractices. The judicial system should be more accommodating both financially and procedurally for minority shareholders.29Continued on Next Page »
BBC NEWS, 'Italian dairy boss gets 10 years'. BBC news (online), I8 December 2008. Available at: http: // news.bbc. eo.uk/go/pr / fr// l/hi/business/7790803.stm (Accessed 28 July 2012).
Buck, T. 'EU seeks-to end bias among shareholders'. Financial Times (online), 16 October 2005. Available at http ://www.ft.com /cms/ s/0/ae l 7a66e-3e6f- l l da-a2cb - 00000e25 I lc8.h tml#axzz21 vL9nllG (Accessed 28 July 2012).
Collyns, C. 'The Crisis though the Lens of History', Finance and Development A quarterly magazine of the IMF, 45. 4 (Dec 2008). Available at: http://www .imf.org!external/pu bs/ft/fandd/2008/12/co llyns.htm (Accessed 23 April 2012).
De Luca, N., 'Unequal Treatment and Shareholders' Welfare Growth: 'Fairness' V. 'Precise Equality", Delaware Journal of Corporate Law (DJCL), 34. 3 (Nov2009). Available at: http ://papers .ssrn.com/so l3/pape rs.cfm?abstract id=l 503089 (Accessed 24 April 2012). pp. 853 - 920.
Holderness , C. G. and Sheehan, D. P. 'The Role of Majority Shareholders in Publicly Held Corporations, An Explanatory Analysis', Journal of Financial Economics20 (1988), pp. 317 - 346.
Hong, F. X. 'Protection of the Shareholders' Rights-at EU Level: How Far Does-It Go?', European Comp any Law 6. 3 (2009), pp. 124-130.
Kalss, S. 'Shareho lder Suits: Common Problems, Different Solutions and First Steps towards a Possible Harmonisation by Means-of a European Model Code', European Company and Financial Law Review6. 2 (2009), pp. 324-347.
Khachaturyan, A. 'The One-Share-One- Vote Controversy in the Elf, European Business Organization Law Review, 8 (2007) pp. 335-367.
Kim, KA., Kitsabunnarat, P. and Nofsin ger, J. R., 'Shareholder Protection Laws and Corporate Boards: Evidence from Europe', Working Paper. Published 1 February 2005. Available at http://fin ance.ba.ttu.e du/new / documents /r esearchSemina rs/ spring 2005 /L aw°/o20and%20Corp ora te%20Govern anc e.pd f (Accessed 23 April 2012).
Lee, J. 'Four Models of Minority Shareholder Protection in Takeovers'. European Business Law Review. 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803- 830.
Levine, R. 'The Governance of Financial Regulation, Reform Lessons from the Recent Crisis', International Review of Finance 12.1 (2012), Available at http: //www.imf.org / external/n p/seminars /eng/2011/res2 /pdf /rl.pdf (Accessed 23 April 2012) pp. 39-56.
Levy, R. E. 'Freeze-out Transactions The Pure Way: Reconciling Judicial Asymmetry between Tender Offers and Negotiated Mergers', West Virgi.nia Law Review 106 (2004) pp. 305-357.
Masauros, P. E. 'Is the EU Taking Shareholder Rights Seriously?: An Essay on the Impotence of Shareholdership in Corporate Europe'. European Company Law7. 5 (2010), pp. 195-203.
McCahery, A. J and Vermeulen, P.M. E. 'Corporate Governance Crises and Related PartyTransactions: A Post-Parmalat Agenda' in Klaus J. Hopt , Eddy Wymeersch, Hideki Kanda, and Harald Baum (eds) Corporate Governance in Context: Corporations, States, and Markets in Europe, Japan, and the US, Oxford; New York Oxford University Press, 2005, pp. 215-246.
Norg es Bank, 'Shareholders rights'. Norges Bank Investment Management (online), Available at http: //www.nbim .n o/en/p ress-and publications/ feature -artides /2006/Shareholde r-rights / (Accessed 02 July 2011).
Sacasa, N. 'Preventing Future Crises Priorities for Regulatory Reform After the Meltdown '. Finance and Development A quarterlymag-azine of the IMF 45.4 (2008) Available at http :/lwww.imf.org:/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2008/ 12/sacasa.htrn (Accessed 23 April 2012).
Szentkuti, D. Milwrity shareholder protection rules in Germany, France and in the UK-A Comparative Overview. Thesis submitted at Central European University. March 2007.
The Commission of the European Communities, 'Commission Recommendation of 15 February 2005 on the role of non-executive or supervisory directors of listed companies and on the committees of the (supervisory) board' . Official Journal of Europ ean Union, 25.2.2005. Available at: http:! /eurlex.europa .eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri =OT:L:2005:052:005 1:0063:EN:PDF (Accessed 01 July 2011).
The Economist, 'What Shareholder Democracy?' The Economist(online), 23 March 2005. Available at http://www.eco n omist.com/node/3 793305?story id=El PSTPPDV (Accessed20 June 2011).
The Economist, 'Europe's revolting shareholders' The Economist(online), 10 Mat 2001 Available at: htt p:/ /www.economist.com/no de/620394 (Accessed on 20 June 2011).
The Free Dictionary by Farlex, 'Majority Shareholder'. Available at: http://fi n ancial-dictionary .thefreedictionar y.com/ Majority+Shareho lder (Accessed 02 July 2011).
Wyckaer, M. and Geens, K 'Cross-border mergers and minority protection: An open-ended harmonization' , Utrecht Law Review 4.l.(M arch2008). pp. 45-52.
Acknowledgements
Authors: Angelika Gorak and Sofiya Kartalova
Angelika Gorak is a graduate of the Department of Law and Criminology, Aberystwyth University.
Sofiya Kartalova is currently pursuing a Bar Profes sional Training Course at BBP University College. She is also a graduate of the Department of Law and Criminology, Aberystwyth University.
Endnotes
- Collyns, C. 'The Crisis though the Lens of History', Finance and Development A quarterly magazine ofthe L.\1.F, 45. 4 (Dec 2008). Available at: http://www.imf.org/exte rnal/ pubs/ft/fan dd /2008/12/collyn s.htm (Accessed 23 April 2012).
- 'Po rtfolio di versification is not enough to manag e credit risk, and it cannot fully repla ce due diligence' quoted in Sacasa, N. 'Preventing Future Crises Prioritie s for Regulatory Reform After the Meltdovm '. Finance and Development A quarterly magazine of the L.\.1.4F5 .4. (2008) Available at http://wv.rw.imf.org/exte rn al/pub s/ft/fa ndd/200 8/12/sacasa .htm (Accessed 23 April 2012).
- Levine, R. 'The Governance of Financial Regulation, Reform Lessons from the Recent Crisis', International Review of Finance 12.1 (2012), Available at: http: II www.imf.org/ extern aVnp/ seminar s/ eng/2011/res2 /pdf /rl.pdf (Accessed 23 April 2012) pp. 39- 56.
- Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minority Shareholder Protection. in. Takeover s'. European Business Law Review. 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803 - 830 (p. 803) .
- 5 Szeutkuti. D. Minority shareholder protection rules ill Germany, France and in the UK-A Comparative Overview. Thesis submitt ed at Central European University. Mar ch 2007, p. 9.
- 6 The Free Dictionary by Farlex., 'Majority Shareholder'. A vailabk at: htt p://financi aldictionary. thefreedict ionary.com/Majorit;y+S hareholder (Accessed 02 July 2011 ).
- Szeutkuti. D. Minority shareholder protection rules ill Germany, France and in the UK-A Comparative Overvi ew. Thesis submitted at Cent ral Europ ean Univer sity. March 2007 , p. 9.
- Levy, R. E. 'Fr eeze-out Transactions The Pur e Way: Reconciling Judicial Asymmetry between Tender Offers and Negot iated Mergers' , West Virginia Law Review 106 (2004) pp . 305-357 (p. 320).
- Levy, R. E. 'Freeze-out Transa ctions The Pure Way: Reconciling Judicial Asymmetr y between Tender Offers and Negotiated Mergers', West Virginia Law Review 106 (2004) pp. 305-357 (p. 320).
- as cited in Levy, R. E. 'Fr eeze-out Transactions The Pure Way: Reconciling Judicial Asymmetry between Tender Offers and Negotiated Merger s', West Virginia Law Review 106 (2004) pp. 305-357 (p. 321 ).
- Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minori ty Shareh older Prot ection in Takeovers '. European Business Law Revi ew. 16. 4. (2005) pp . 803 ~ 830 (pp. 805-808).
- Wyckaer , M. and Geens, K. 'Cross-border mergers and minorit y protection: An open-ended harmonization ', Utrecht Law Review4.l.(March 2008). pp. 45-52. (pp. 45-47).
- Holdern ess, C. G. and Sheehan, D. P. 'The Role of Majority Shareholders in Publicly Held Corporations, An Explanatory Analysis' , Journal of Financial Economics 20 (1988), pp. 317 -346.
- McCahery, A. J and Vermeulen, P.M E. 'Corporate Governa nce Crises and Related Party Transactions: A Post -Parmalat Agenda' in Klaus f. Hopt, Eddy Wymeersch, HidekiKanda, and Harald Baum (eds) Corpo rate Governance in Context: Corporations , States, and 1vfarkets in Europe, Japan, and the US, Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press, 2005, pp. 215-246 (p. 220).
- BBC NEW"S, 'Italian dairy boss gets 1 O years '. BBC news (on line), 18 December 2008. Available at: http://news.bbe.co . uk /go/pr/fr/ -fl/hi!bus incss/7790803. stm (Accessed 2 8 July 2012) .
- McCahery, A. J and Vermeu len, P.M E. 'Corporate Governance Cris.es and Related Party Transaction s: A Post-Parmalat Agenda' in Klaus J. Hopt , Eddy Wyrneersch , Hideki Kanda, and Harald Baum (eds) Corpora te Governance in Context: Corporations, States, and 1..\1.arketisn Europe, Japan, and the US, Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press, 2005, pp. 215 - 246 (p.220) .
- McCahcry , A. J and V crmeu len , P.M E. 'Corporate Governance Crises and Related Party Transaction s: A Post-Parmalat Agenda' in Klaus J. Hopt , Eddy Wyrneersch , Hideki Kanda, and Harald Baum (eds) Corporate Governance in Context: Corporations, States, and Markets in Europe, Japan, and the US, Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 2005, pp. 215 - 246 (p.220) .
- Directive 2004/25/EC ofth_e European Parliarnentand of the Council of 21 april2 004 on takeover bids
- Lee, f. 'Four Mod els of Minori ty Sharehold er Prot ection in Takeovers '. European Busin ess Law Revi ew. 16. 4. (2005) pp . 803 ~ 830 (p. 803, p. 807)
- 20 Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minority Shareho lder Protection in. Takeovers' . European Business Law Review . 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803-830 (p. 809-813) .
- 21 For an. extend ed discu ssion of the EU' s prote ction of sharehold ers, see appendix .
- 22 ( 1843) 2 Hare 461.
- Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minority Shareholder Prot ectio n in Takeovers' . European Business Law Review. 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803-830 (p. 814).
- Kalss, S. 'Shareholder Suits: Common Problems, Differ ent Solutions and First Steps towards a Possible Harmonisation by Mean s of a European Model Cod e', European Company and Firnmcial Law Review 6. 2 (2009), pp. 324-347 (pp. 339-340) .
- Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minorit y Shareholder Protection in Takeovers' . European Business Law Review. 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803 - 830 (p. 815).
- Kim. K. A., Kitsabunnarat, P. and Nofsinger, J. R., 'Shareholder Prote ction Laws and Corporat e Boards: Evidence from Euro pe', Working Paper. Publi shed 1 Februa ry 2005. Available at: http ://finance.ba.tt u.edu /new/do cumcn ts/ researchSeminar s/spriug2005/Law%20and%20Corporate%20 Governance.pd f (Acces.sed 23 April2012) .
- Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minority Shareholder Protection in Takeovers'. European Business Law Review . 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803-830 (p. 815).
- Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minority Shareholder Protection in Takeovers'. European Business Law Review. 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803-830 (p. 817).
- Lee, f. 'Four Models of Minority Shareholder Prot ection in Takeovers'. European Business Law Review. 16. 4. (2005) pp. 803-830 (pp. 817-818).
- The Economi st, 'Europe's revoltin g shareholder s' The Economist(on line), 10 Mat 2001 Available at: h ttp ://www .econmnist.co m/ nod e/620394 (Accessed on 20 June 2011).
- Hong, F. X. 'Protect ion of the Shareho lders ' Rights at EU Level: How Far Does It Go?', European Company Law 6 . 3 (2009) , pp. 124-130. (p. 124).
- Norges Bank, 'Shareho lders right s'. Norges Bank Investment Aianagement (onli ne), accessible at http: II www.nbim .no/ en/pr ess-and -pub lications/feature -articles/2006 /SharehoWer -rights/ ( Accessed 02 July 2011) .
- Hong, F. X. 'Protection of the Shar eholder s' Right s at EU Level: How Far Does It Go?' European Comp any Law6. 3 (2009), pp. 124-130 (p. 124-125).
- McCahery, A. J and Vermeulen , P.M E. 'Corpora te Govern ance Cris.es and Related Party Tra nsactions: A Post-Parmalat Agenda' in Klaus J. Hopt , Eddy Wymeersch, Hideki Kand a, and Harald Baum (eds) Corporate Govern ance in Cont ext Corporation s, States, and Markets in Europ e, Japan, and the US', Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press, 2005, pp. 215-246 (p.220).
- McCahcry, A. J and V crmeulen, P.M E. 'Corpora te Governan ce Crises and Related Party Tran sactions: A Post-Parm alat Agenda' in Klaus J. Hopt , Eddy Wymeersch, Hidek i Kand a, and Harald Baum (eds) Corporate Governanccin Cont ext: Corporatio ns, States, and Market s in Europe, Japan, and the US, Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press, 2005, pp. 215-246 (p. 220) .
- Khachatur yan, A. 'The One-Share-One-Vote Controversy in the EU', Europ ean Business Orga nization Law Review, 8 (2007) pp . 335 -367.
- The Commission of the European Communiti es, 'Commission Recommendation of 15 February 2005 011 the role of non-executive or supervisory dir ectors of listed companies and on the committees of the (supervisory) board '. Official Journal of European Union, 25.2.2005. Available at http:/lc urlcx.curopa .eu/LcxUr iServ/LexUriScrv.do?uri =Of:L:2005:052:0051:0063:EN:PDF (Accessed 01 fuly2011) .
- http:IIwww.nbim.no /en/ pre ss-and -publicat ions/fcature -articles/2006 /SharehoWer -rights/ ( Accessed 02 July2011).
- The Economist, 'What Sharehold er Democracy?' The Econ omist( onlinc), 23 March 2005. Available at http :l!www.econ.omist.com/nod e/3793305?story id=El PSTPPDV (Accessed 20 Tune 2011).
- The Economist, 'What Share hold er Demo cracy?' The Economist(online) , 23 March 2005. Available at htw://www. ecorromist. com/nod e/3793305?story id=El PSJPPDV(A ccessed 20 Jun e 2011).
- Buck, T. 'EU seeks to end bias among shar eholders'. Fin ancial Times (on line), 16 October 2005. Available at http :ffwww.ft.comfcms fs/Ofael7a66e-3e6f-ll da-a2cb--OOOOOe12l5c8 .html#axzz2 1vL9n llG (Accessed 28 July 2012).
- These grant special rights to the holder irrespective of his equity stake.
- A proh ibition to vote above certa in thr eshold , irrespective of the numb er of share s.
- Khachaturyan, A. 'The One-Share- One-Vote Contro versy in the EU', European Business Organi zation Law Review, 8 (2007) pp . 335-367 (p. 16).
- De Luca, N. 'Unequal Treatment and Shareholders' Welfure Growth : 'Fairness' V. 'Precise Equality", Delaware Journal of Corporate Law (DJCL), 34. 3 (Nov 2009). Available at : http ://papers .ssrn .com/sol3/pape r s.din.?abstract i.d=l503089 (Accessed 24.April 2012). pp. 853-920 (pp. 871-873).
- De Luca, N. 'Unequal Treatment and Shareholders' Welfure Growth: 'Fairness' V. 'Precise Equality", Delaware Journal of Corporate Law (DJCL), 34. 3 (Nov 2009). Available at :http:// papers.ssrn.com!soB/papcrs.cfm?abstractid=l503089 (Accessed 24 April 2012). pp. 853-920 (p.875).
- Masauro s, P. E. 'Is the EU Taking Shareholder Rights Seriously?: An Essay on the Impote nce of Shareholdersh ip in Corporate Europe ' Europea n Compa ny Law 7. 5 (2010), pp . 195-203 (p. 203).
Suggested Reading from Inquiries Journal
In spite of the above-described traditional sentiment that the European Union (EU) was primarily an economic actor, with all other priorities seconded to that fact, trade policy has been inextricably linked with the EU’s international presence since the inception of the Common Commercial Policy (CCP) from the Treaty Establishing... MORE»
Does candidacy to the European Union (EU) increase a nation’s Trade Openness? A good way to begin examining this question is by asking, what is Trade Openness? Simply put, it is a nation’s imports plus its exports... MORE»
The Economic Monetary Union (EMU) is the end point of an ambitious and historic stage of integrated market changes1 that not only challenge the structure and foundation of modern-day liberal capitalism, but also offer – where successful – a wealth of opportunity in the goods, labour and service industries of the European Union. A fiscal extension to the principles of the Schengen Agreement2 of 1985 offered a financial breakthrough where... MORE»
The subject of European legal integration entered the spotlight of interdisciplinary studies in the mid-1990s and has continued to maintain, if not increase, its prominence in scholarly literature (Mattli and Slaughter,... MORE»
Latest in Economics
2020, Vol. 12 No. 09
Recent work with the Economic Complexity Index (ECI) has shown that a country’s productive structure constrains its level of economic growth and income inequality. Building on previous research that identified an increasing gap between Latin... Read Article »
2018, Vol. 10 No. 10
The value proposition in the commercial setting is the functional relationship of quality and price. It is held to be a utility maximizing function of the relationship between buyer and seller. Its proponents assert that translation of the value... Read Article »
2018, Vol. 10 No. 03
Devastated by an economic collapse at the end of the 20th century, Japan’s economy entered a decade long period of stagnation. Now, Japan has found stable leadership, but attempts at new economic growth have fallen through. A combination of... Read Article »
2014, Vol. 6 No. 10
In July 2012, Spain's unemployment rate was above 20%, its stock market was at its lowest point in a decade, and the government was borrowing at a rate of 7.6%. With domestic demand depleted and no sign of recovery in sight, President Mariano Rajoy... Read Article »
2017, Vol. 9 No. 10
During the periods of the Agrarian Revolt and the 1920s, farmers were unhappy with the economic conditions in which they found themselves. Both periods witnessed the ascent of political movements that endeavored to aid farmers in their economic... Read Article »
2017, Vol. 7 No. 2
In 2009, Brazil was in the path to become a superpower. Immune to the economic crises of 2008, the country's economy benefitted from the commodity boom, achieving a growth rate of 7.5 per cent in 2010, when Rousseff was elected. A few years later... Read Article »
2012, Vol. 2 No. 1
The research completed aimed to show that the idea of fair trade, using the example of goals for the chocolate industry of the Ivory Coast, can be described as an example of the economic ideal which Karl Marx imagined. By comparing specific topics... Read Article »
|